Categories
Economical policy Euro zone

Europe’s response to the pandemic

The Next Generation EU recovery plan is a remarkable innovation that enables the European Commission to pay €750 billion (divided between grants and loans) to the twenty-seven member countries, based not on their ‘relative weight’ but on the needs of each country and shared objectives. But it is also a major innovation because this recovery plan also allows Europe, for the first time, to raise a common, joint debt of the same amount.

The result of the historic agreement reached between France and Germany, this plan represents an important step forward in the necessary construction of a stronger, more effective and more united European Union. It was particularly appropriate that this plan was welcomed as major European progress. Without, however, going so far as to describe it as Europe’s ‘Hamiltonian moment’. In 1790, Alexander Hamilton, the first Secretary of the Treasury of the United States, organised the takeover by the federal government of the debts of the various US states, which had been considerably increased by the War of Independence. At the same time, he established import duties, a source of recurrent federal revenue. Hamilton, leader of the Federalist Party, thus enabled the United States to take a decisive step in its federal construction. Europe has not gone that far.

To begin with, this significant development itself is currently hampered by several types of dysfunction and obstacles. The disbursement of grants and loans appears slow and complex to implement. Now that the European Parliament has adopted the plan, it must be approved and ratified by all twenty-seven national parliaments before it can be implemented, and the twenty-seven countries will have to justify to the European Commission the use of their subsidies and the reforms necessary for their economy. This is no doubt an understandable requirement before committing to such an act of solidarity, but it is unfortunately slow and complex and incompatible with the immediate financing needs of the States, at a time when a slower recovery is being announced for the European Union, with growth forecasts for 2021 of +4.4% compared with +6.4% in the United States, which will also have slowed down much less in 2020 (-3.5%, compared with -6.8% for Europe).

Moreover, there is no guarantee that such a Community budget will be maintained in the future and that the accompanying common debt can be renewed. Many so-called “frugal” countries have already suggested that this is just a “one off” operation, linked only to the existence of the pandemic. Therefore, the timely implementation of these instruments will not necessarily lead to the construction of a more federal Europe.

Moreover, the pandemic is considerably accelerating many changes that were under way in all areas. Europe is obviously not immune to these changes, but it is not well placed in the new growth sectors of the economy. It must therefore quickly consider pooling more resources to increase and accelerate investment in these areas. This is what the Next Generation EU plan intends to do, but perhaps not commensurate with the challenges of global economic and technological competition. In order to participate in the renewed dynamism of the world economy and be a player in the new sectors driving growth, it is necessary for Europe, an old civilisation, not to lose its vitality, its taste for innovation and its capacity to take risks. The precautionary principle alone cannot serve as a guide to prepare for the future.

Furthermore, it is becoming urgent to resume the institutional construction of the Union and at least of the eurozone. If it is to defend its integrity and its social market model in the long term, it must be both economically efficient and united. The necessary structural policies must therefore be conducted on a country-by-country basis in order to reassure the ‘frugal’ countries that they will not have to pay for the ‘spendthrift’ countries ad infinitum, in exchange for the implementation of elements of a transfer union. A European investment policy to re-industrialise the regions with a deficit is also an additional and essential condition. Structural policies alone – assuming they are effectively implemented – will not be enough. Europe will also have to face the fact that the countries that make up Europe will emerge from the pandemic with even greater disparities than when they entered it.

Lastly, it must develop a common strategy to exist on the international scene between the two superpowers, the United States and China, if it wishes to carry weight in the future in the international arena, by defending its values as well as its political, diplomatic and economic weight.

If Europe’s leap forward in the face of the pandemic is clearly to be welcomed, European ambition must bounce back with a certain sense of urgency, by making the essential changes, particularly in terms of institutional regulation, if it is to meet the substantial challenges of the present time. The road will not be easy, but time is running out.

Categories
Economical policy Euro zone

Europe’s response to the pandemic

“A crisis offers an unmissable opportunity to move forward.” This was the conclusion of ELEC international’s position paper last June: “Let’s use the Next Generation EU Fund as a driver for change.” With the adoption for the first time of a common recovery plan and a Community loan to finance it, Europe is moving forward and has a great opportunity to assert a better way of regulating the Union of 27.

The Next Generation EU recovery plan is a remarkable innovation that will enable the European Commission to disburse €750 billion (divided between grants and loans) to its twenty-seven member countries, based not on their “relative weight” but on the needs of each country and on shared objectives. But it is also a great innovation because, for the first time, this recovery plan also allows Europe to raise a common, joint debt of the same value.

Born of the historic agreement between France and Germany, this plan represents an important step forward in the necessary construction of a stronger, more efficient and more united European Union. It was particularly appropriate to see this plan being welcomed as a major European step forward. However, describing it as Europe’s “Hamilton moment” might be a little strong. In 1790, Alexander Hamilton – the first Secretary of the Treasury of the United States – arranged for the federal government to cover the debts of the various American states, which had been considerably increased by the War of Independence.

At the same time, it established import taxes – a source of ongoing federal revenue. In doing so, Hamilton – the leader of the Federalist Party – enabled the United States to take a decisive step forward in its federal construction. Europe has not gone that far. And promising developments are currently being held back by several types of failure and obstruction.

To begin with, the disbursement of grants and loans appears slow and complex to implement. Now that the European Parliament has adopted the plan, it must be approved and ratified by all twenty-seven national parliaments before it can be implemented, and the twenty-seven countries will have to provide evidence to the European Commission of the use of their subsidies and the supporting reforms necessary for their economy. Such a requirement is no doubt understandable before undertaking such an act of solidarity, but it is unfortunately slow and complex, and incompatible with the immediate financing needs of the States, at a time when a slower recovery is being predicted for the European Union, with growth forecasts for 2021 of +4.4% compared to +6.4% in the United States, which also experienced much less of a slowdown in 2020 (-3.5%, compared to -6.8% for Europe).

In addition, there is no guarantee that such a Community budget will be maintained in the future and that the accompanying joint debt can be renewed. Many “frugal” countries have already suggested that this is essentially a “one-off” operation, linked only to the existence of the pandemic. The expedient implementation of these instruments will not necessarily lead to the construction of a more federal Europe. This is why this hardly constitutes a “Hamilton moment” for the Union.

Furthermore, the pandemic is considerably accelerating many across-the-board changes that were already under way. Europe is obviously not immune to such changes, but it is not well placed in the new growth sectors of the economy. It must therefore quickly consider pooling more resources to increase and accelerate investment in these areas. Of course, this is what the Next Generation EU plan intends to do, but perhaps not to an extent that really addresses the challenges of global economic and technological competition. In order to participate in the renewed dynamism of the world economy and be a player in the new growth sectors, it is necessary that our Europe – an old civilisation – does not lose its vitality, taste for innovation and ability to take risks. The precautionary principle alone cannot serve as a guide to the future.

It is therefore becoming an urgent priority to resume the institutional construction of the Union, or at least of the euro zone. If it is to defend its integrity and its social market model in the long term, it must be both economically efficient and supportive. The necessary structural policies must therefore be conducted on a country-by-country basis in order to reassure the “frugal” countries that they will not have to go on subsidising the “spendthrift” countries forever, in exchange for the implementation of aspects of a transfer union. A European investment policy that reindustrialises regions running a deficit is also a complementary and necessary condition. Structural policies alone – even assuming they are effectively implemented – will not be enough. Europe will need to face the fact that its countries will emerge from the pandemic with even greater disparities than when they entered it.

It also needs to develop a common strategy for existing on the international scene between the two hyperpowers – the United States and China – if it wishes to be a player in the future in the international arena, where it can defend its values as well as its political, diplomatic and economic weight.

Finally, the example of the EU’s joint vaccination purchasing policy also reveals the various obstacles that can impede the construction of a united and ambitious Europe. The practical and generous idea of a “Vaccine Union” had the virtue of avoiding unhealthy competition between the twenty-seven Member States for doses – thus favouring the richest at the expense of the others – and could demonstrate the power of the European model by guaranteeing equitable access between the Member States by means of distribution in proportion to their populations. Negotiating on behalf of all countries, whether they had a pharmaceutical industry or not, meant giving priority to consensus-building, negotiating hard on prices, preferring European producers, and rigorous compliance with procedures. At a time when the United Kingdom and the United States were applying a “whatever it takes” policy in terms of vaccine purchases, the Union was losing precious time in the race to vaccinate, even though the health of all its citizens and its economic recovery depended on its speed.

Lastly, we should somewhat qualify the numerous criticisms and comments questioning the management of the pandemic by Europe, and by France for that matter. A simple reminder seems appropriate: no one is yet able to state the ultimate results, effects, consequences and outcomes… or even the exact origin of the virus! A recent study by France Stratégie aimed at identifying the true mortality rates of Covid at global level raises major questions over the international comparisons made since the beginning of the pandemic, and calculation methods in particular, which vary from one country to another. Using the excess mortality rate, i.e. the ratio of expected to observed deaths, as a basis for comparison, we can see that Europe is the second least affected region in the world, behind the Far East. It also appears that France has been much less badly affected than the average European country. The time to take stock will come later.

Although Europe’s response to the pandemic is clearly to be welcomed, Europe’s ambitions are facing many practical and institutional obstacles, too often based on differences of interest between EU members. Europe must bounce back with a clear sense of urgency, making the necessary changes, particularly in terms of institutional regulation, if it is to face up to the significant present challenges. The road will not be an easy one, but time is running out. It is for this reason that our League must continue its efforts by bringing its thoughts to the debate, in order to promote an efficient and dynamic Europe, strong in its values and its economy.

Categories
Economical policy Global economy

HOW CAN WE AVOID THE DEBT TRAP AFTER THE PANDEMIC?

The longer the pandemic lasts, the more governments need to support the economy, and rightly so, particularly companies in the most affected sectors and the households that depend on them, and the more central banks need to support governments by buying their additional debt. As a consequence of this, debt is strongly increasing. Post-Covid, the question is how this sharp spike in debt will be managed, coming as it does after a period of rising debt globally for at least the last two decades. This is how the ‘debt trap’ is built.  Either central banks will gradually exit their quantitative easing policy and long interest rates will rise again, potentially causing the insolvency of a number of companies and States, if they have not returned to a credible debt trajectory before.  Or they will not do it and it will exacerbate the financial and real estate bubbles already present with soon or later their bust and their disastrous economic and social consequences.  And, ultimately, a possible loss of confidence in money. What policies can we then pursue to best avoid this trap?

 There are wrong paths and others to consider, as no solution is obvious or easy.

FIRST WRONG PATH

First wrong pathis the one defended by a number of economists who say that, fundamentally, debt can be limitless because interest rates are close to zero. More specifically, with nominal interest rates below nominal growth rates, debt sustainability would be assured. Thus, de facto, debt levels would ultimately have little importance. But the underlying model, which is well known, is only true under certain conditions.

FOUR REASONS WHY THIS MODEL SHOULD BE CALLED INTO DOUBT:

First, this situation of interest rates persistently lower than growth rates almost inevitably generates financial cycles, that is bubbles on assets (particularly equities and real estate, but also gold, art, etc.), with an excessively strong and under-rewarded trend towards over-indebtedness and risk-taking among investors (households and asset managers). Ultimately, this leads to greater vulnerability in both borrowers’ liabilities and investors’ assets. Major financial crises arise sooner or later, with now well-known economic and social consequences. In addition, these crises reduce potential growth over the long term. These issues are now well documented, so we will not make the case for this point here, as it is clearly explained elsewhere. Finally, we should add that macroprudential policies, however essential they are, remain wholly insufficient to counter financial cycles. On the one hand, because they remain national and it is difficult for authorities to act against the competitiveness of the banks in their own country, on the other, above all because they only affect banks at this time, while the relative weight of financial markets in the national and international financing system has been rising sharply over the last few decades.

Secondly, notwithstanding the financial crises caused, excessively low rates for too long are themselves weighing on growth trends. This is not always well understood. In the usual model, the natural interest rate, calculated on the basis of determinants that are real variables, has been getting ever lower for several decades. It has even been very low in recent years, or even below zero in the eurozone. The extremely low or even negative natural rate could be a sign that savings are above ex-ante investments and inflation is too low, below its target. This would therefore justify taking effective rates ever lower to drive savings down and investment up, and raising the inflation rate at the same time. However, perhaps there is an anomaly in this reasoning. This idea, while partly true, is also partly mistaken, because the monetary regime, that is the monetary policy that unfolds over the long term, also in reality influences the economy and growth over the long term.

Thus, if interest rates are below growth rates for too long, monetary policy affects the real economy by the resulting misallocation of capital. Some companies in fact stay alive, while if interest rates had been close to the growth rate, they would have continually shown a loss and would have actually disappeared (these companies are called “zombies”). They stay alive, distort capital allocation, disrupt the health of healthy and competitive companies, and prevent the natural phenomenon of destruction/creation necessary for any economic dynamism in developed countries. This is one of the reasons behind the decline in productivity gains. Moreover, excessively low interest rates for too long also facilitate debt. It is much easier to borrow when the interest rate is continually below the growth rate. And over-indebtedness inevitably leads to a decline in investment, which again has a negative impact on productivity gains.

To continue our demonstration, consider the traditional model according to which lower interest rates lead to lower savings and higher investment, which holds true in normal times. In reality, if interest rates are below the growth rate for too long and close to zero, this sooner or later leads to an increase in savings. We should accept that money illusion can play a role in this. We have seen this recently (even before the pandemic), with households accumulating much more savings to offset the lack of interest received, in order to reach the capital they deem necessary for their retirement despite everything.  We should add that persistently low interest rates for a long time also weigh on company expectations. Under this scenario, we are likely to see very low nominal growth in the future, which does little to encourage an entrepreneurial spirit. Moreover, zero or negative interest rates muddle all economic calculations.

Finally, if interest rates are excessively low for too long, this creates bubbles, leading to wealth inequalities that, in addition to the resulting social consequences, may have a negative impact on consumption. It is not the households with the highest propensity to consume that generate the most wealth.

For all the reasons set out above, there is therefore a clear trap in keeping rates too low for too long. A non-monetary and non-financial model has to be used to believe that finance and money do not have a significant impact on the real economy. Yet, history has proved the contrary.

In order to avoid deflation and allow the economy to rebound, it is clearly necessary to bring interest rates below growth rates during a major crisis, including through quantitative easing policies when interest rates are already very low, particularly during over-indebtedness crises such as that of 2007-2009. But keeping them very low and below the growth rate, when growth has returned, lending is back at its normal levels, etc., leads to a structural weakening in growth, through the mechanisms described above. And then, it leads in turn to ever lower interest rates.

Finally, note that in the usual model, the Phillips curve indicates that the more employment increases, the more inflation rises. Thus, the same model indicates symmetrically that while inflation remains very low, below its target, the economy is still far from full employment. That is, savings are higher than investment, ex ante. This also indicates that the natural interest rate, a modelled and unobservable variable, is below the effective interest rate, thus pointing to the need to push the latter further downwards. But for years, and up to the current period at least, the Phillips curve has not been working any more, with full employment no longer driving the rise in prices.

This means that taking interest rates ever lower during periods of “normal” growth, in search of a lower natural interest rate, may result from a partially erroneous interpretation. An interpretation that could have a negative impact on the economy, given the effects described above. The question, then, of the inflation target, during this inflation regime, at a level below but close to 2%, would become critical.

 We believe that too low inflation is dangerous, as it carries with it a significant probability of falling into deflation, due to the impossibility of making flexible adjustments allowing private agents to react to a recession without triggering massive lay-offs or numerous bankruptcies. Excessively low inflation means it is no longer possible to bring down real interest rates or real wages, factors in less economically and socially painful adjustments. But, if structural inflation remains very low, significantly below 2%, for a long period in the economy, due to the effects of globalisation and the technological revolution, does seeking to raise it at all costs, through a permanently ultra-accommodative monetary policy, not lead to all the very negative effects explained above due to interest rates being below growth rates for too long? We believe central banks must maintain an inflation target, that is to say must have a nominal anchor objective, but the chosen targets must be adapted to the long-term economic and financial regime in force. The monetary policy conducted by central banks must in fact make it possible to achieve both monetary and financial stability.

 Third reason: the idea that interest rates below growth rates ensure countries’ long-term solvency is based on a series of heroic assumptions. First, the assumption that inflation will not bounce back significantly for a long time. Indeed, inflation is unlikely to pick up in the immediate future, but, in a few years, who knows whether US policy will not revive inflation with a very high budget deficit, wage hikes, etc.? How will a possible very strong recovery after Covid affect prices? With bottleneck effects and a lack of well-trained labor forces adapted to the growing economic sectors.  What will be the effect of the reorganisation of certain production and supply chains? Finally, what effect will the cost of the necessary energy transition have on inflation in the middle and long term? A degree of inflation would be valid and useful, as long as it does not turn into an inflationary regime, that is to say generalized indexation. But if inflation were to stay above its target for the long term, either central banks would react, and given the considerable amount of debt, would induce private and public insolvencies that could trigger a catastrophic chain of events, specifically  if the announced debt trajectory is not under control or not credible; or central banks would not react, and would therefore expose themselves to a dangerous loss of credibility due to their inability to control inflation. They are indeed guarantors of the nominal anchor, i.e. moderate inflation.

Moreover, even without any significant increase in inflation, if central banks were no longer to buy almost all of the excess public debt, because growth returned to normal for example, there would need to be buyers replacing central banks themselves. The idea that investors would limitlessly be willing to buy debt at zero or negative interest rates seems unrealistic. This is why both retail and institutional investors, as we have seen, take disproportionate risks to obtain small returns. 

 Finally, it is not only for interest rates to rise for the usual sovereign solvency equation to indicate that conditions have not been met. Indeed, even if interest rates remained at their current levels for a long time, a fairly sustainable and strong shock could lead to a drop in the growth rate itself, thereby jeopardising the expected solvency trajectory. Even a prolonged worsening primary deficit could undermine solvency, even if facilitated in parallel by an interest rate that is lower than the growth rate.

  So, there is effectively a debt trap, whether there is a surge in long-lasting and undesired inflation or not.  If central banks let rise or raise rates, whether for reasons of a return  to normal growth and full employment or to meet their inflation targets if inflation climbs up, the effects on a heavily indebted economy  will only be bearable if both governments and private agents have announced and started a credible solvency trajectory.  And if central banks do not do this, they are the ones who will lose their credibility, triggering destabilizing monetary and financial, and ultimately economic and social, potentially catastrophic dynamics.  Including the destructive dynamic of flight from money, analyzed below.

Fourth reason: if debt increases constantly due to the effect of magic money, the monetary constraint, i.e. the payment constraint, will be increasingly ineffective. However, as Michel Aglietta rightly says, confidence in money is the alpha and omega of society. The monetary system is a debt settlement system. Confidence in money is therefore based on the fact that the debt settlement system gives us confidence by being effective. If households can spend more than they earn over the long term, if companies can finance their losses without limits, if governments do not have any constraints on growth in their debt, it is the monetary system itself that will no longer be effective or credible. The very value of money will thus be questioned, and sooner or later, a flight from the currency, with the appearance of non-bank private currencies, cryptocurrencies, etc. We can easily imagine, and it is already under way, that the GAFAs, more solvent than countries and managing gigantic quantities of trade and settlement, could issue their own currency. Will households ultimately prefer to have this type of currency in this case? It would be very dangerous and destructive for society. Gold, as well as some real assets, could also be lies of escape from money. Think of German hyperinflation, assignats, etc. The payment of compensation required by the winners of the World War I forced the German government to disburse much more than it was capable of. The central bank was forced to finance this. It then ran after hyperinflation, always printing the amount of money necessary to enable spending. This led to the emergence of local private currencies, such as those from large companies, which issued bonds with very small denominations that could serve as currency instead of the mark. This situation proved destructive for society.

SECOND WRONG PATH

Second wrong path: a number of other economists want to cancel partially or totally the debt held by central banks. Note that the idea expressed is uncorrelated to that on which the first path is based. Cancelling debt can only be indispensable if the amount of debt at stake is unsustainable. The two proposals are therefore antinomic.

 The idea of debt dumping by central banks does not hold up. On the one hand, governments and central banks must be considered as a consolidated entity in order to have a true vision of the mechanisms at stake. As central banks are mostly owned by governments, what a central bank earns is therefore earned by governments. Cancelling debt, on the other hand, would lead to a serious loss of credibility for both central banks and governments. Experience through history shows that public debt cancellations are only very rarely successful, and that on the contrary they lead to very heavy costs over time. The cancellation of the debt therefore seems outright unthinkable.

THIRD WRONG PATH

         Third wrong path: to raise taxes, particularly wealth tax. First, the amounts of these taxes are in no way comparable to the amount of debt. The scales are totally different. In some countries, where taxes are low, we can fully understand that increasing taxes helps towards the solutions to be put in place. In France, taxes over GDP are among the highest among developed countries, including the current capital tax rate, which remains, even after reform, one of the highest among comparable countries. Such an increase would therefore be very dangerous for demand. As it would be very dangerous for supply, as here, once again, it is necessary, during the reconstruction phase, to encourage entrepreneurs to do business and innovate, and to foster competitiveness. This would promote both an increase in production capacity and the country’s appeal. Moreover, the number of start-ups is increasing significantly at the moment. This phase of powerful mutation, which Covid did not create but is accelerating considerably, must be well supported.

FOURTH WRONG PATH

         Fourth wrong path: Mandatory Government issued Bonds consist of drawing off a portion of household savings to finance government debt. With savings abundant due to the pandemic, this idea seems to be gaining traction. It is undoubtedly true that savings have increased sharply during the pandemic among households, but also among companies that have been little or unaffected by it. However, there are several possible analysis errors in this idea. First, such a mandatory government issued bond would most likely be perceived as confiscatory, and would significantly reduce trust in governments, which, given the world’s current state, does not seem desirable. Secondly, there would be a subsequent reconstruction of assets, because households would be afraid of not being repaid in the future or seeing the amounts due to them eroded by long-term inflation. This would have an adverse impact on consumption, resulting in an increase in savings. What’s more, the situation is completely different from the immediate post-war era, which saw households hoarding their cash under their bed. The idea was then to mobilise unproductive savings. Today, the European economy is fully banked. 99% of households in France have one or more bank accounts. When they put money aside, it is mostly in bank deposits. Savings are therefore mobilised by banks to lend to the economy. This savings is neither idle nor unproductive. A mandatory government issued bond would move savings that finance the private economy to financing the government.

HOW THEN CAN WE GET OUT OF THE DEBT TRAP?

  First of all, corporate debt. In France, we know that the corporate debt-to-GDP ratio has risen significantly in the last decade, faster than the eurozone average, and has now exceeded it. We therefore need to increase companies’ capital in relation to debt. Participation loans are a way forward, but is not the only way of doing this, because they are still debt, even subordinated, and they are relatively expensive. Convertible bonds should undoubtedly also be considered, for example. In any event, households must be encouraged to mobilise part of their savings towards companies’ capital by improving their taxation in such cases or by guaranteeing a portion of the capital thus invested. We should also bear in mind that banks and insurance companies have seen their regulatory capital required on their capital investments in companies increase significantly under Basel 3 and Solvency II. Would it not, at least temporarily, be useful for the European economy and even ultimately favourable to banks’ risk exposure, to reduce the regulatory capital cost of such investments?

For public debt, it would be necessary first to distinguish Covid debt and accept that the excess public debt due to Covid could be refinanced for an extended period of time on a “rolling” basis by the central bank. Like that of companies, government debt is in reality not strictly speaking extinguished. At maturity, they are repaid by issuing new debt, at current market conditions. The important thing for the issuer is therefore not to reduce its debt whatever happens, but to ensure a solvency trajectory that allows subscribers to be found for its new issues at subsequent maturities, and this under “normal” conditions. In order to avoid overly burdening public debt market during future refinancing, in order to avoid compromising government solvency for a sufficiently long period of time, central banks could thus ensure over a sufficiently long period of time the refinancing of the excess public debt due to the pandemic alone. This would not correspond to any cancellation or permanent monetisation of public debt.

Raise the potential growth:

  Secondly, it is essential to raise the nominal growth rate in order to make public debt more easily sustainable. Stronger growth generates more income for governments, which has a favourable impact on the balance of public finances, as well as on GDP, and therefore on the numerator and denominator of the public debt ratio. The debt ratio is therefore improved in two ways.

 We must not pursue an austerity policy, because we must not enter this vicious circle. In order to increase growth rates, we must pursue policies to support demand, until we see a return to a “normal” growth rate. But structural policies are also essential. Their goal is to increase growth potential. The essential reform of the State in France would improve the efficiency of the money spent and ultimately improve the economy’s competitiveness factors. French public expenditure is higher, in proportion to GDP, than that of most European economies, and its ultimate efficiency is too low. Its comparative performance, measured in terms of PISA and PIAAC scores, or measured by the wage level of nurses, for greater expenses in the sector of education or health, which are just a few examples among many others, clearly shows this. The French poor ranking in terms of equal opportunities (and not equality of income after redistribution, which, conversely, is one of the best among OECD countries) is another example of the way forward to improve the value of the public money spent. But these reforms are difficult to implement during economic crises and do not have a rapid effect. However, they remain essential.

 Pension reform, consisting of increasing the number of annuities to take account of demographic change, is highly effective and has faster results. The deficit in the pension system is a major contributor to the public deficit. It is easy to understand that as we are living longer, as examples overseas clearly show, we need to increase the number of annuities we pay in order to be entitled to a full pension. This reform, which is invaluable in controlling public spending, would also be additional proof that France is taking the problem of debt seriously. Finally, pension reform does not undermine growth; on the contrary, it makes it possible to encourage French people to save less by easing or even dispelling their fear of not having a sufficient or predictable pension. And because this reform increases the active population, it increases the growth potential, at a time when we will need everyone in order to produce more.

 The reform of unemployment insurance may also be of use to potential growth. Even in this period, the number of jobs that go unfilled remains high. We would seem to need unemployment insurance that does more to encourage people to find a job, while creating a marker of the various allocation criteria according to labour market indicators. At the same time, however, we need to strengthen people’s security and protection, if we are justifiably to make jobs more flexible. Current and future accelerated economic changes will require us to change profession and company even more than before. Better personal protection, particularly through better initial training and more intensive and effective professional training, is therefore an essential corollary.

CONCLUSION

 Thus, in order to avoid a step backwards in renewed growth, monetary policy support and fiscal stimulus clearly need to continue until stable growth is restored.

But it will quickly be necessary to give a clear commitment from States, like central banks, to pursue a trajectory over several years making it possible to return to the “normal” and to stick to it in a scrupulous manner, to give confidence in the debt and in fine in the money. Unlimited debt development would cause very serious monetary and financial crises, even if the timing is difficult to predict.  Commitment to a medium-term path of sustainability of public finances, in particular by increasing growth potential and without excluding the necessary financing of investments that promote sustainable growth, is essential.  Equally necessary is the commitment to a gradual and prudent return of monetary policy to a practice of driving nominal interest rates towards nominal growth rates when growth is satisfactory.”

It has indeed been clearly known since the last great financial crisis that a satisfactory and steady growth rate and a controlled inflation rate and on target are not enough to lead to the absence of bubbles and financial crises.  Monetary policy must therefore simultaneously seek economic stability (by closing the “output gap”), monetary stability (by closing the inflation gap between the observed inflation rate and the target pursued) and financial stability (by preventing as much as possible – and not just repairing – bubbles in the financial and real estate markets, as well as abnormal increases in the debt-to-GDP ratio).

In the medium term, this is a narrow way out, but probably the only one feasible.

 Biography

Artus Patrick

“Does the ECB’s inflation target need to be revised?” 

Natixis Flash Economie, 22 October 2019, no. 1421

https://www.research.natixis.com/Site/en/publication/srO6u1dWo9TfV-S4A51_G5Yqna5_bOSvBCe_Ds2V9tI%3d?from=email

Banerjee & Hofmann

“Corporate zombies”

BIS Working Papers 882 – 2 September 2020

https://www.bis.org/publ/work882.htm

Blanchard Olivier & Pisani-Ferry Jean

“Monetisation: Do not panic”

(Vox EU) – 10 April 2020

https://voxeu.org/article/monetisation-do-not-panic

Blinder Alan S.

“Monetary and financial stability in a low interest rate environment: challenges ahead”

BIS Papers No. 98, July 2018

https://www.bis.org/publ/bppdf/bispap98.pdf

Borio Claudio

“Monetary policy and financial stability: what role in prevention and recovery?”

BIS Working Papers no. 440

https://www.bis.org/publ/work440.htm

Borio Claudio

“What anchors for the natural rate of interest?”

BIS Working Papers 777, 26 March 2019 – (page 1 to 16)

https://www.bis.org/publ/work777.htm

Borio Claudio

“The expectations on central banks are simply too great”

Speech, 21 November 2019

https://www.bis.org/speeches/sp191121.htm

Carstens Augustin

“Maintaining sound money compliance and after the pandemic”

Bis speech, 8 October 2020

https://www.bis.org/speeches/sp201008.htm

Couppey-Soubeyran Jézabel, Bridonneau Baptiste, Dufrêne Nicolas, Giraud Gaël, Lalucq Aurore, Scialom Laurence

“Cancel the public debt held by the ECB and ‘take back control’ of our destiny”

Le Monde, 5 February 2021, also published in the following European media: L’Avvenire (Italy), El Pais (Spain), La Libre Belgique (Belgium), Paperjam (Luxembourg), Der Freitag (Germany), Infosperber (Switzerland), Le Temps (Switzerland), Euractiv (EU)

https://cancellation-debt-public-bce.com/

Draghi Mario

“Monetary policy and structural reforms in the euro area”

Speech, Bologna, 14 December 2015

https://www.ecb.europa.eu/press/key/date/2015/html/sp151214.en.html

ECB

“The natural rate of interest”

December 2019

https://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/pdf/scpops/ecb.op217.en.pdf

de Larosière Jacques

“Breaking the monetary policy deadlock”

Les Echos – 12 September 2019

https://www.lesechos.fr/idees-debats/cercle/sortir-la-politique-monetaire-de-limpasse-1130969

François Villeroy de Galhau: The tale of the three stabilities: price stability, financial stability   and economic stability

https://www.banque-france.fr/en/intervention/tale-three-stabilities-price-stability-financial-stability-and-economic-stability

https://www.bis.org/review/r210304d.htm

Goodhart Charles

“Inflation after the pandemic: Theory and practice”

Vox, June 2020

https://voxeu.org/article/inflation-after-pandemic-theory-and-practice

Goodhart Charles, Schulze Tatjana and Tsomocos Dimitri

“Time inconsistency in recent monetary policy”

Vox, 4 August 2020

https://voxeu.org/article/time-inconsistency-recent-monetary-policy

Klein Olivier

“The Current Financial Crisis : something old, something new”

Article published in Revue Sociétal no. 65 – Q3 2009. 
https://www.oklein.fr/en/the-current-financial-crisis/  

Klein Olivier / Dubreuil Thibault

“Exiting the ECB’s highly accommodative monetary policy: issues and challenges”

Financial Economy Review – 5 December 2017
https://www.oklein.fr/en/exiting-the-ecbs-highly-accomodating-monetary-policy-stakes-and-challenges-2/

Klein Olivier

“When is the next financial crisis?”

Aix meetings, 6 July 2019
https://www.oklein.fr/en/when-will-the-next-financial-crisis-happen/

Klein Olivier

“Low interest rates: too much of a good thing”

La Tribune, 1 September 2020
https://www.oklein.fr/en/low-interest-rates-too-much-of-a-good-thing/

Klein Olivier

“The debt issue: risk of financial instability and of a loss of trust in money”

EURO 50 Conference, 14 December 2020
https://www.oklein.fr/en/the-debt-issue-risk-of-financial-instability-and-of-a-lost-of-trust-in-money/

Lowe Philip

“Some Echoes of Melville”, Speech, 29 october 2019        https://www.bis.org/review/r191101b.pdf

Categories
Economical policy Euro zone

Central banks digital currencies : benefits and hazards

While cash payments shrink, a phenomenon accelerated by the pandemic, and in response to the growing attraction of private cryptocurrencies and the lead taken by certain countries including China, the European Central Bank (ECB) too is now considering the possibility of creating its own digital currency.

A digital central bank currency can be a “wholesale” currency used between banks and the central bank – in this case, other than technically, the economy of the monetary system as a whole scarcely changes – or a central bank currency held by the public, thus co-existing with physical banknotes, also issued by central banks.

For some of the public and depending on the country, the importance of fiat money to better protect privacy varies. This is why the ECB is careful to state that it will create a digital currency alongside and not instead of fiat money, and to specify that the ECB “cryptocurrency” could potentially guarantee the anonymity of its users. In countries where banks are relatively inaccessible because branch networks are much less dense, a central bank digital currency could well increase financial inclusion.

Why do central banks want to launch such currencies, beyond the legitimate interest of not lagging behind new technologies? The fundamental reasons are their no less legitimate interest in preserving the effectiveness of certain transmission channels from monetary policy to the economy. And their need to have (monetary) contact with the general public, which could diminish, and possibly vanish, with the gradual reduction in the use of banknotes. Competition with private cryptocurrencies does not seem to me to be an argument, however, because it is down to the banking currency denominated in the national currency (or in euros, in the case of the eurozone), and therefore down to the “official” currency system as a whole, to be more credible than private (crypto) currencies, and not down to central banks alone.

While the intentions are perfectly understandable, however, care should be taken to ensure that this desire to create a digital euro does not cause financial instability. It must not be the case that at the slightest concern, whether well-founded or not, about the banking system as a whole or a particular bank, massive transfers occur from bank accounts to the central bank’s digital currency. The possibility of panic would consequently be considerably increased. To guard against this hazard, the ECB is considering capping deposits in its digital currency. If the ceiling was not very low (less than an individual holds in banknotes in their wallet on average), the creation of such a currency would potentially precipitate the possibility of systemic risk.

Moreover, such a currency – whether it is held in accounts in commercial banks or not does not change anything – in insufficiently small quantities could raise fears that a significant portion of bank deposits will gradually evaporate, thereby automatically diminishing the role of commercial banks as financial intermediaries. In the long term, it is even conceivable that deposits could be entirely held in digital central bank currencies, ultimately forcing commercial banks to refinance almost exclusively on the financial markets or with central banks to secure credit. This would then seriously damage the economy; under-estimating the role of commercial banks, the fundamental economic role of which is to be a centralised centre for risk, would have serious economic consequences. By transforming deposits, the desired duration of which is generally very short-term, into loans with an average maturity in the medium to long term, banks essentially shoulder the liquidity and interest rate risks that economic stakeholders, households and businesses do not know about or want to take. This role is extremely useful, because it underpins the proper functioning of the financial system, which consists of aligning the financing capacities of some parties with the financing needs of other parties, given that they rarely spontaneously match in terms of maturities, liquidity, and appetite for credit risk.

Lastly, the creation of a dollar-denominated central bank digital currency by the Fed could precipitate dollarization of the economies of countries with weaker currencies, which would further reduce their room for manoeuvre in terms of economic policy.

It is therefore crucial that central banks make the right decision, and make their calibrations and adjustments, with due consideration of both the benefits and the challenges and hazards of such innovation in terms of the ultimate effectiveness of financing the economy and financial stability. The potential risks could, otherwise, be significant.

Categories
Economical policy Euro zone

The post-Covid economic paths are very narrow

This much is obvious: the longer the pandemic lasts, the higher the debt will be. To counter the economic effects of the lockdowns, governments and central banks have taken powerful and vital desensitising actions. After the pandemic, they will have to reduce, and then end them. With the very good outlook brought by the vaccines, fortunately; but this phase is when the economic crisis will gradually surface, with a rise in bankruptcies and lay-offs in the affected sectors. Then will come the “debt trap”. Either the central banks will pull out of their quantitative easing policy little by little, and long-term interest rates will rise, triggering the insolvency of many companies and governments, if the latter do not find a new credible trajectory for their debt. Or they do not, and fuel the financial and real estate bubbles that exist already, which after a while would pop, bringing disastrous economic and social consequences. And, ultimately, a possible loss of confidence in money. What paths could be taken to best escape falling into this debt trap?

Cancelling the debt, a mandatory government bond issue or tax hikes are not real solutions.

Cancelling the public debt is an idea that makes no sense – as it is a zero-sum game – which is very dangerous for the credibility of a country. A mandatory government bond would be considered confiscatory. It would lead to a drop in consumption to build up savings. Savings that these days are no longer stored under the bed, but used by banks to finance loans. Lastly, taxing wealth would not make any more sense given the extent of the stakes at hand and the absolute necessity to value entrepreneurs and innovators in these changing times. A general tax rise in France, where mandatory contributions are among the highest in the world, would have a negative impact on both demand and supply.

A “Covid debt”: It would be necessary for the ECB to continue warehousing the higher government debt resulting from the pandemic over a fairly long period of time, to avoid a loss of confidence of the markets if they suddenly had to take on this part of the public debt purchased by the central banks over the period.

But the fundamental solution lies in an increase in potential growth. In the hope that controlled inflation will also come and contribute to solving the debt issue. The vital reform allowing the government to improve its efficiency will have to be launched later. The pension reform can be made now. It would contribute greatly to reducing the public deficit. Longer life expectancy requires increasing the number of annuities. Which would increase potential growth, thanks to a rise in the participation rate, and incite the French to save less, having greater confidence in their future pensions.

The unemployment benefits system also has to be reformed: the number of jobs that go unfilled remains high. The formula currently proposed, which could adjust different allocation criteria according to job market indicators, appears to be well adapted. The essential corollary: the need for individual protection, notably via a more intensive and more efficient professional training strategy to support employees during the major transformations underway.

Lastly, coming out of the Covid era, what will the economic policy mix be? The support and stimulus fiscal and monetary policies need to remain in place as long as there has not been a return to a stabilised level of growth. Austerity must be avoided. But the governments and the central banks will quickly have to commit to following a path to a return to “normal” over several years to install confidence in the debt and money. The idea that near-zero interest rates mean that there is no need to worry about debt is based on a theory according to which money and finance are neutral. History has proven the contrary. The exit paths described here are narrow, but are probably the only ones possible without significantly further exacerbating the risks.


Original column from Les Echos 16th Feb 2021

This much is obvious: the longer the pandemic lasts, the higher the debt will be. The real economic difficulties are therefore ahead of us. To fight the effects of the pandemic, governments and central banks have taken powerful and vital desensitising actions. After the pandemic, they will have to reduce, and then end them. This phase is when the economic crisis will gradually surface, with a rise in bankruptcies and lay-offs. Then will come the “debt trap”. Either the central banks will pull out of their quantitative easing policy little by little, and long-term interest rates will rise, triggering the insolvency of many companies and governments, if the latter do not find a new credible trajectory for their debt. Or they do not, and fuel the financial and real estate bubbles that exist already, which after a while would pop, bringing disastrous economic and social consequences. And, ultimately, a possible loss of confidence in money. What paths could be taken to best escape falling into this debt trap?

Cancelling the debt, a mandatory government bond issue or tax hikes are not real solutions. Cancelling the public debt is an idea that makes no sense – as it is a zero-sum game – which is very dangerous for the credibility of a country. A mandatory government bond would be considered confiscatory. This would lead to a drop in consumption to build up savings. Lastly, taxing wealth would not make any more sense given the extent of the stakes at hand and the absolute necessity to value entrepreneurs and innovators in these changing times. A general tax rise in France, where mandatory mandatory contributions are among the highest in the world, would have a negative impact on both demand and supply.

Increasing potential growth will be key in order to face the debt problems. The vital reform allowing the government to improve its efficiency will have to be launched later. The pension reform can be made now. It would contribute greatly to reducing the public deficit. Longer life expectancy requires increasing the number of annuities. This would increase potential growth, thanks to a rise in the participation rate, and incite the French to save less, having greater confidence in their future pensions. The unemployment benefits system also has to be reformed: the number of jobs that go unfilled remains high. The formula currently proposed, which could adjust different allocation criteria according to job market indicators, appears to be well adapted. The essential corollary: the need for individual protection, notably via a more intensive and more efficient professional training strategy to support employees during the major transformations underway.

Lastly, coming out of the Covid era, what will the economic policy mix be? The support and stimulus fiscal and monetary policies need to remain in place as long as there has not been a return to a stabilised level of growth. Austerity must be avoided. But the governments and the central banks will quickly have to commit to following a path to a return to “normal” over several years to install confidence in the debt and money. The idea that near-zero interest rates mean that there is no need to worry about debt is based on a theory according to which money and finance are neutral. History has proven the contrary. The exit paths described here are narrow, but are probably the only ones possible without significantly further exacerbating the risks.

Categories
Economical policy Event

TASK FORCE Carbon Pricing in Europe

I had the pleasure and the honor to introduce this webinar, the opportunity to recall our convictions and our strategy to leave a low carbon world to future generations :

« I am honored to introduce the topic of our meeting today.

Thank you, dear Edmond.

Of course, now, everybody is conscious of the real, huge and present danger of carbon emissions for the planet and of the urgency of the energy transition.

It is an usual issue in economics, by the way, because air is a common good. And non private goods, common goods, are always complex issues to deal with. The question is :  who is responsible for these common goods ?

  • As far as individuals are concerned, having a free rider attitude is always a human inclination.
  • As far as Nations are concerned, they can ask themselves how accountant are they, as a Nation, for global warming. They could easily expect other Nations to bear the costs of decreasing carbon emissions, leaving the others to do the job. And we should stress that some countries, and not the smallest, play or played this game.

To help the situation, we can think of several solutions :

  1. Norms : legal constraints.

Yes, but it is not obvious to establish these norms because a lot of them can be in effect inefficient, or even sometimes counterproductive. And they have to be simultaneously established in a lot of countries, because if some important countries are not on board, the efforts won’t be successful and there won’t be fair competition.

  1.  The same with subsidies.
  2. Public opinion, may be part of the solution, reinforced by name and shame. Though, with the risk of focusing on false solutions,  politically correct but sometimes of poor or nil efficiency.
  3. Carbon Price :

It’s now a consensus among the economists that it is the best approach. Because it is the only holistic method to influence individuals as well as corporates behavior. On top of that, this solution preserves entrepreneurial and consumer freedom.

Though, it is still complex to be implemented : price setting is still an issue. Should there be a market for emission rights ? Should there be a carbon tax ?

And there are some other pregnant issues :

  1. The difficulties for those who have to bear the brunt of the consequential increase in carbon price and its impact on their purchasing power (the “Gilets Jaunes” effect).

So, what system of compensation should be implemented, if any ?

  • There are still diverging interests among Nations :
    • between rich and poor Nations
    • between industrialized and less industrialized
  • As far as Europe is concerned, a carbon price increase should go hand in hand with taxes at the European Union boarders, to avoid seriously disadvantaging the EU.

But, is it possible for the 27 countries to agree on this point ?

Conclusion :

This is the reason our task force dedicated to the carbon pricing solution has been created by Edmond Alphandery.

In order to foster the spread of this idea and to push forward possible solutions to these crucial issues, in Europe and across the Globe.

That is why Bred, AXA and Meridiam decided to support the task force on carbon pricing in Europe. »